Hide table of contents

TL;DR

EA might be unterutilizing direct contact of politicians through constituents, especially by phone calls, letters, and email. There is evidence that relatively little effort can have a significant effect, as long as voters call with a specific agenda, frame their concerns appropriately, and the topic is not highly polarized.

The Hypothesis

In this post I’m focusing on grassroots-style advocacy, where a number of people contact their respective representatives in order to nudge them into voting in a certain way with respect to specific legislations. I focus on calling, and writing emails and letters, or maybe even visiting politicians in their hometown offices; it’s not meant to be exhaustive, surely there’s more to investigate here.

I see three main settings: 1) parliament will vote on a law and you want to influence the politicians’ voting behavior; 2) parliament is planning on voting on a law, but the proposed law could use some improvements; and 3) you have an idea for a new law or a modification of another recent law. I think all three would need different considerations (and there are probably more), however, I will not differentiate between them - this is only meant as a short note.

I do realize that certain actors in the EA (and adjacent) space might actually use grassroots-style direct contact of politicians (especially in the animal advocacy space). However, it does not seem to get any attention in the “mainstream” EA community. A lot of people are interested in EA and want to participate in a meaningful way beside donating, but without making a complete career switch. I have the impression that the community is turning these people down, with the argument basically being that there’s not really that many effective things to do for volunteers. I think that giving this an “official stamp of approval” would make a huge difference (obviously conditioned on the EA community actually thinking that it is effective).

There has been some talk about what a “Task Y” could be, a task that is effective and helpful, where a lot of people can participate without too much time commitment, and that also gives them the feeling that they are really contributing something valuable. I have the impression that influencing your politicians might be a partial answer to this question.

Epistemic status

These are preliminary thoughts and I am looking for feedback. I spent a weekend going through some literature and sorting my ideas, but I don’t have any domain expertise in the area. I might be overly optimistic since I’m easily excitable.

Would this have any effect at all?

There is considerable evidence that politicians are influenced by direct contact of their constituents. Staffers and politicians are eager to claim that calls, letters, and emails do have an effect on their policymaking, and there exist many anecdotes of laws that have been passed and/or modified based on constituent-input. There are some observational and even a few randomized studies indicating that these effects actually exist. In one special case, a small number of (randomized) calls to representatives led to a ~11-12 percentage point increase in voting in favour of a certain law compared to the control group. I’m far from calling these data conclusive yet, though.

Importantly, this all depends a lot on the kinds of laws under question. For highly partisan or polarized topics - immigration, guns, abortion, … - calling your representative will probably have no effect at all (exceptions exist, of course, but they usually require extreme amounts of constituents and media attention). Most evidence for effectiveness I found was focused on more innocuous topics, such as a school bullying law in response to a student suicide, or making certain government documents more user-friendly.

In essence: there is some evidence suggesting that contacting politicians on non-polarized topics should be reasonably effective.

Do these kinds of issues actually exist?

In topics such as health care reform and mental health, or in animal advocacy, there should be quite a number of laws that would have a considerable net-positive effect.

Two examples:

In early 2020, the German government voted on whether to make organ donation the default with the possibility to opt-out, vs making it opt-in, but asking citizens at some points when they visit a citizens’ office. I have the impression that the first option would be very much more aligned with EA-values - there’s practically no cost, everyone can still decide for themselves, and lots of lives would be expected to be saved (correct me if I’m wrong, please!). Although votes in the German parliament are usually divided along party lines, this one had members of all parties vote in all directions. The vote was relatively close, and the opt-in solution was accepted. A certain nudging of politicians might have helped change this outcome.

Another example might be to ban chick culling, so that it will be replaced e.g. by in-ovo sexing, a technology that as far as I can tell exists, but is not yet cost-effective enough. Most people (including meat eaters) don’t like the idea of killing billions of one-day-old chicks, it seems quite obviously EA-aligned, and a law banning (or heavily fining) the practice would probably speed up the wide-spread introduction of alternative technologies by many years.

On the other hand, I’m much more sceptical when it comes to long-termist causes, or highly complex topics where it really depends a lot on the fine print.

Is it really cost-effective?

I really don’t know yet. Some of the evidence suggests that even a few dozen calls can influence a single politician to a sufficient degree on certain topics, while others might need thousands or tens of thousands of calls and still might not have the desired effect. I would expect an average call, email or letter to cost anything between 5 minutes and two hours. A direct visit of a politician (e.g. at their local offices) might be a couple of hours. The effect if successful obviously depends on the law in question.

As a side note, I would also argue that 1,000 people spending one hour might have a very different value than 1 person spending 1,000 hours, i.e.: the cost of a project is not simply a linear function of the number of hours (and money invested etc), but depends on how these hours are distributed among different people. If we could mobilize 1,000 people to spend one hour, counterfactually they might have spent this one hour with free-time, they might gain a significant degree of meaning and community-involvement from this one hour and potentially making it quite positive for them; this increased involvement in the EA community might even lead to people identifying more with the ideals and donating more. The one person spending 1,000 hours to start a new project might have a very different experience, especially if the project turns out to be unsuccessful (which most projects probably are?).

One potentially substantial problem might be that many offices get a lot of calls, letters, and emails - numbers vary a lot, depending on source, political season, external events, nation & state, and many more, but one anchoring number might be several thousand contacts per “normal” week. Standing out among those many contacts might require a large amount of people, but I would expect this to depend also on the concrete issue.

All this does not yet include overhead costs - we would need to find useful laws to influence, we would need to organize the campaign, we would need to evaluate the effectiveness. We’d also need to incorporate potential negative effects, of course.

The right format

The main argument I’m making is with respect to calling, emailing or writing letters, or meeting politicians in person. The first three all have different pros and cons, with different sources citing different ones as the most effective. E.g. written letters and calls are more personal and hence might be more persuasive, but emails can be better indexed by the data processing software the politicians’ offices use (they seem to be very out-of-date).

Most sources discount online petitions as virtually worthless (although there might be exceptions if politicians can verify that it’s their very own voters who signed the petition). I found little up-to-date work on social media (esp. Twitter & FB), but the evidence that I found seemed quite negative. I’m not sure how demonstrations compare to these methods.

On small scale problems, organizing more along these lines might also be feasible.

Different countries, different rules

Effectiveness and cost-effectiveness might be quite different for different democracies. E.g. the US system makes politicians quite responsible to their constituents, so they might be very inclined to listen to them. In Germany by contrast, decisions are usually made on the level of parties; however, I would assume that fewer people might be actually contacting their representatives, making it easier to cut through the noise.

What are the potential risks?

Two general policy problems are that a) we might inadvertently be supporting the wrong side of an argument (or politicians might misunderstand what we are saying); and b) we might divert attention from more cost-effective and more relevant, but a-little-harder-to-achieve causes/methods by luring EAs into a less-than-optimal easy-win area. I do think this would require some more detailed and quantitative analysis of the evidence, and potentially some pilot tests. In general, many of the risks mentioned here apply to some degree, but I also think that some of them might be less pronounced since we're talking about smaller forms of more indirect nudges.

Most other risks I see are related to the (cost-)effectiveness. For one, this approach might require too many people to be involved, and too much time commitment of those (they would need to regularly contact their officials). This also expands to the potentially large amount of organizational overhead. This effect is exacerbated by the fact that different countries have very different political mechanisms - each country would require independent work.

On the other hand, we might not find sufficiently many laws/low-hanging fruits worth promoting - maybe they just don’t exist (policy is hard), or they are too hard to find.

I also imagine the whole process to be relatively hard to quantify; although I can think of several techniques on how to gather semi-reliable data, it’s by no means trivial and would require non-negligible amounts of empirical research. This also entails the possible failure to realize so if it turns out to not be an effective way of improving policies.




I have many more thoughts, but this post is already way longer than I had planned for it. I’m interested in what others think about the whole topic, whether I’m making any inferential mistakes, whether I’m overlooking any opposing evidence, or if people would be interested in exploring this further.

17

0
0

Reactions

0
0

More posts like this

Comments3


Sorted by Click to highlight new comments since:

Yes, that's quite relevant - was there any follow-up or evaluation of the effects? And is there any particular reason why this was only a one-time thing?

We basically lost momentum, and the group member with professional lobbying experience moved away.

More from _matt_
Curated and popular this week
 ·  · 13m read
 · 
Notes  The following text explores, in a speculative manner, the evolutionary question: Did high-intensity affective states, specifically Pain, emerge early in evolutionary history, or did they develop gradually over time? Note: We are not neuroscientists; our work draws on our evolutionary biology background and our efforts to develop welfare metrics that accurately reflect reality and effectively reduce suffering. We hope these ideas may interest researchers in neuroscience, comparative cognition, and animal welfare science. This discussion is part of a broader manuscript in progress, focusing on interspecific comparisons of affective capacities—a critical question for advancing animal welfare science and estimating the Welfare Footprint of animal-sourced products.     Key points  Ultimate question: Do primitive sentient organisms experience extreme pain intensities, or fine-grained pain intensity discrimination, or both? Scientific framing: Pain functions as a biological signalling system that guides behavior by encoding motivational importance. The evolution of Pain signalling —its intensity range and resolution (i.e., the granularity with which differences in Pain intensity can be perceived)— can be viewed as an optimization problem, where neural architectures must balance computational efficiency, survival-driven signal prioritization, and adaptive flexibility. Mathematical clarification: Resolution is a fundamental requirement for encoding and processing information. Pain varies not only in overall intensity but also in granularity—how finely intensity levels can be distinguished.  Hypothetical Evolutionary Pathways: by analysing affective intensity (low, high) and resolution (low, high) as independent dimensions, we describe four illustrative evolutionary scenarios that provide a structured framework to examine whether primitive sentient organisms can experience Pain of high intensity, nuanced affective intensities, both, or neither.     Introdu
 ·  · 2m read
 · 
A while back (as I've just been reminded by a discussion on another thread), David Thorstad wrote a bunch of posts critiquing the idea that small reductions in extinction risk have very high value, because the expected number of people who will exist in the future is very high: https://reflectivealtruism.com/category/my-papers/mistakes-in-moral-mathematics/. The arguments are quite complicated, but the basic points are that the expected number of people in the future is much lower than longtermists estimate because: -Longtermists tend to neglect the fact that even if your intervention blocks one extinction risk, there are others it might fail to block; surviving for billions  (or more) of years likely  requires driving extinction risk very low for a long period of time, and if we are not likely to survive that long, even conditional on longtermist interventions against one extinction risk succeeding, the value of preventing extinction (conditional on more happy people being valuable) is much lower.  -Longtermists tend to assume that in the future population will be roughly as large as the available resources can support. But ever since the industrial revolution, as countries get richer, their fertility rate falls and falls until it is below replacement. So we can't just assume future population sizes will be near the limits of what the available resources will support. Thorstad goes on to argue that this weakens the case for longtermism generally, not just the value of extinction risk reductions, since the case for longtermism is that future expected population  is many times the current population, or at least could be given plausible levels of longtermist extinction risk reduction effort. He also notes that if he can find multiple common mistakes in longtermist estimates of expected future population, we should expect that those estimates might be off in other ways. (At this point I would note that they could also be missing factors that bias their estimates of
 ·  · 3m read
 · 
We’ve redesigned effectivealtruism.org to improve understanding and perception of effective altruism, and make it easier to take action.  View the new site → I led the redesign and will be writing in the first person here, but many others contributed research, feedback, writing, editing, and development. I’d love to hear what you think, here is a feedback form. Redesign goals This redesign is part of CEA’s broader efforts to improve how effective altruism is understood and perceived. I focused on goals aligned with CEA’s branding and growth strategy: 1. Improve understanding of what effective altruism is Make the core ideas easier to grasp by simplifying language, addressing common misconceptions, and showcasing more real-world examples of people and projects. 2. Improve the perception of effective altruism I worked from a set of brand associations defined by the group working on the EA brand project[1]. These are words we want people to associate with effective altruism more strongly—like compassionate, competent, and action-oriented. 3. Increase impactful actions Make it easier for visitors to take meaningful next steps, like signing up for the newsletter or intro course, exploring career opportunities, or donating. We focused especially on three key audiences: * To-be direct workers: young people and professionals who might explore impactful career paths * Opinion shapers and people in power: journalists, policymakers, and senior professionals in relevant fields * Donors: from large funders to smaller individual givers and peer foundations Before and after The changes across the site are aimed at making it clearer, more skimmable, and easier to navigate. Here are some side-by-side comparisons: Landing page Some of the changes: * Replaced the economic growth graph with a short video highlighting different cause areas and effective altruism in action * Updated tagline to "Find the best ways to help others" based on testing by Rethink