Researcher focused on China policy, AI governance, and animal advocacy in Asia.
Currently transitioning from a researcher role at Good Growth to projects at the intersection of China x AI.
Also interested in effective giving, economic development (and how AI will affect it), AI x Animals, wild animal welfare, cause prioritisation, and various meta-EA topics.
My ideas for posts (I'll try to write at least one):
Agree with your point about the Chinese study reference, about healthy aging for elderly Chinese people. The OP uses it to make three separate points, about cognitive impairment, dose-response effects and lower overall odds of healthy aging, but it's pretty clear that the study is basically showing the effects of poverty on health in old age.
Elderly Chinese people are mostly vegetarian or vegan because a) they can't afford meat, or b) have stopped eating meat because they struggle with other health issues, both of which would massively bias the outcomes! So their poor outcomes might be partly through diet-related effects, like nutrient/protein deficiency, but could also be sanitation, malnutrition in earlier life (these are people brought up in extreme famines), education (particularly for the cognitive impairment test), and the health issues that cause them to reduce meat.
The study fails to control for extreme poverty by grouping together everyone who earned <8000 Yuan a year (80% of the survey sample!), which is pretty ridiculous, because the original dataset should have continuous data...
The paper also makes it very clear that diet quality is the real driver, and that healthy plant-based diets score similarly to omnivorous diets "with vegetarians of higher diet quality not significantly differing in terms of overall healthy aging and individual outcomes when compared to omnivores".
Probably less importantly, it conditions on survival to 80, which creates a case of survivorship bias/collider bias. So there could be a story where less healthy omnivores tend to die earlier (you get effects like this with older smokers, sometimes), and the survivors appear healthier.
I agree with the upfront tagline "Having children is not the most effective way to improve the world", but feel I disagree pretty strongly with a bunch of these takes:
I'm very torn on this question, so let's shoot for 60%.
Many people are probably thinking about the impact on animals, which most EA forum readers will probably agree is a far stronger argument for anti-natalism than climate.
There's a set of arguments, recently articulated by Bentham's Bulldog, which looks like this:
Of course we should take this argument seriously, but:
1) Having children seems an incredibly inefficient way of maximising your destruction of insects! If insect suffering does overwhelm other effects, this fails to provide an effective utilitarian argument for human pronatalism.
2) Based on current human values and preference for environmental protection/rewilding, it seems plausible to me that the marginal human may not decrease wild insect numbers. Similarly, I can see a far-future where more humans make the world worse for both farmed and wild animals.
3) Practically, I suspect you'll lose most ethically minded individuals, or people who have very low estimates of insect/fish consciousness, at step 2 - the meat-eater problem. Step 3 requires taking quite a bitter pill in terms of cross-species anti-natalism and the disvalue of existence more generally. "Open Phil-brand EA", which generally disregards insect and wild animal welfare, would also have to reject step 3, and may therefore have to conclude that anti-natalism is good.
4) More personally, it does seem a bit weird feeling that my wonderful little baby's main source of value in the world is his insect-destroying potential.
Maybe you read it, maybe just a coincidence, but I wrote a blogpost that (using a toy model) found Uzbekistan to be the most promising country for incentivising birth rates!
I'll push against this post a little bit, despite agreeing with a lot of the ideas.
Firstly, I think we can avoid the moral discomfort of "hoping for warning shots" by reframing as "hoping for windows of opportunity". We should hope and prepare for moments, where, for whatever reason, policymakers and the public are unusually attentive to what we're saying.
Secondly, while you're more arguing against the hand-wavy "warning-shot as cavalry" claims, there seems to be another claim- that we should act in a similar way regardless of whether or not the "warning shot" model is correct, i.e. whether we expect the policy and discourse battle to take the form of a gradual grind of persuasion vs. a very lumpy, unpredictable pattern shaped around distinct windows of opportunity.
Our strategy might look similar most of the time, and I agree that a lot of the hard persuasion work in the trenches needs to go on regardless. But I suspect there are a few ways you might act differently if the "warning shot/windows of opportunity" model is correct. For example:
I spent some time researching this topic recently (blog post link). It seemed an odd paradox - why does the one-child policy not seem to have that much of an impact on the birth rates?
The answer is quite simple but weird that no-one knows about it. It's mainly that the pre-One Child Policy population control policies in China in the 1970s were more restrictive than you think, and the 1980s policies were de facto more liberal. You can see this 1970s crash on any visualisation- from 6 to 2.7 births per women in 7 years! (1970-1977). A big chunk of this was because the legal marriage age shot up in most areas, to 25/23 for rural women/men, and 28/25 for urban. You get a big gap where people, especially in villages, would previously be having kids at 18 and suddenly weren't.
Thanks to Deng's reforms, the 1980s were more open in many ways, marriage was restored to the normal age, divorce was liberalised, so the one child policy was implemented partly to stop a resurgence of the birth rate! So alongside a big wave of sterilisations, you also get the "catch-up" of people now allowed to marry and have kids. Also, after some pushback, the OCP wasn't that strictly enforced in the late 1980s, especially in rural areas, so you get some provinces where 3 or 4 kids stayed normal. Some people also took advantage of Deng's reforms to leave their village, get divorced and have a kid with someone else. So you don't see a big crash in the birth rate in the 1980s, and China averaged 2.5 kids per woman in the mid 1980s.
The OCP was more strictly enforced in the 1990s, so you see the crash from 2.5 to 1.5 births per women then. You also start seeing the extreme sex ratio imbalances. Now that the 1990s (56% male) cohort has reached parent-age, that's one reason the current crash in the birth rate is so extreme. China would probably be seeing drops in the birth rate in the absence of any population control policies, but there's no chance it would be this extreme.
Yeah, this is a big challenge in the corporate campaign space, especially in places with weak legal systems and low enforcement. But this links to why corporate campaigns can be more effective than policy campaigns. Getting policy commitments on paper in a country with poor rule of law might have very limited impact because no-one's incentivised to uphold the laws, but there's a decent chance that an international, or niche company with high reputational awareness is incentivised to try and maintain a higher welfare supply chain.
So you might get a high-end hotel chain in a lower-income country that genuinely wants to shift to cage-free eggs after a campaign. They make a commitment, you arrange meetings with them and their suppliers to help them meet these commitments, and track whether their numbers match up. This can work even if the legal system functions poorly.
People in the Bharat Initiative for Accountability (BIA) and Global Food Partners (GFP) are doing stuff like this in India and Southeast Asia. It takes loads of work on both the supply and demand side, as you might expect, which might cut against the higher-end effectiveness estimates, but it's definitely something people have in mind.
People from these teams spoke about this recently on the How I Learned To Love Shrimp podcast (here and here).
https://www.morganstanley.com/ideas/obesity-drugs-food-industry This study doesn't make Semaglutide look especially promising for animal welfare (increase in poultry and fish), but I'm not sure how rigorous the research is, so I'd be excited to read other sources.
Thanks for the post! This is a very valuable topic, and the development econ mainstream is totally lost on this question!
I agree with some of your points, but I think we need to distinguish very carefully between "developing countries". All the factors you mention with regards to labour displacement (structure of the economy, data availability, telecommunication infra) are wildly different between, say, Togo, Brazil, and Indonesia. Same with private- vs. public sector diffusion; within "developing countries", you've got countries with massive tech hubs and their own tech billionaires, and those where most people still don't have electricity.
For me, the most important development question with regards to TAI (and the reason it's important to distinguish) is the feasibility of the export-led development model. Generally, if countries manage to develop a high-value added export sector, they attract FDI, get foreign currency, climb up the value chain, and become richer. If they don't, they stay poor. Except for the occasional country finding insane levels of natural resources, this is the only real way that countries have become rich over the last 100 years.
If we get safe, transformative AI, we can imagine that demand for imports massively rises in the West, and middle-income countries like China, Vietnam, and Indonesia with strong export sectors (and the infrastructure to build on their existing exports) are able to take advantage of this. As these countries already have good infrastructure (e.g. electrification, internet access, land and shipping transport) they can probably also benefit from AI & Robotics to develop "Industry 4.0" and make their export sector even more dominant.
I'd therefore estimate that a few of these "developing" countries with existing strong export sectors will catch-up and become rich relatively soon.
But what of the poorest countries?!
Most African countries with a GDP below, say $3000 are very low down the value chain in all sectors, with little but raw materials (e.g. coffee, cocoa, oil if they have it) as exports. They're struggling to compete with Asian developing powerhouses, and they haven't got the transport infrastructure, governance, or capital etc. to develop a quality export-led economy. In a world without TAI, as middle-income countries get rich, poor countries would develop the export industries and climb the ladder themselves, but this seems very unlikely with displacement of manufacturing labour by robotics.
My overall take is that (in an optimistic AI scenario) well-governed middle-income countries would probably end up more similar to rich countries. But we'd have really "kicked away the ladder" from the very poor countries.