Hide table of contents

This is a linkpost for a paper I wrote recently, “Endogenous Growth and Excess Variety”, along with a summary.

Two schools in growth theory

Roughly speaking:

In Romer’s (1990) growth model, output per person is interpreted as an economy’s level of “technology”, and the economic growth rate—the growth rate of “real GDP” per person—is proportional to the amount of R&D being done. As Jones (1995) pointed out, populations have grown greatly over the last century, and the proportion of people doing research (and the proportion of GDP spent on research) has grown even more quickly, yet the economic growth rate has not risen. Growth theorists have mainly taken two approaches to reconciling [research] population growth with constant economic growth.

“Semi-endogenous” growth models (introduced by Jones (1995)) posit that, as the technological frontier advances, further advances get more difficult. Growth in the number of researchers, and ultimately (if research is not automated) population growth, is therefore necessary to sustain economic growth.

“Second-wave endogenous” (I’ll write “SWE”) growth models posit instead that technology grows exponentially with a constant or with a growing population. The idea is that process efficiency—the quantity of a given good producible with given labor and/or capital inputs—grows exponentially with constant research effort, as in a first-wave endogenous model; but when population grows, we develop more goods, leaving research effort per good fixed. (We do this, in the model, because each innovator needs a monopoly on his or her invention in order to compensate for the costs of developing it.) Improvements in process efficiency are called “vertical innovations” and increases in good variety are called “horizontal innovations”. Variety is desirable, so the one-off increase in variety produced by an increase to the population size increases real GDP, but it does not increase the growth rate. Likewise exponential population growth raises the technology growth rate from the positive rate that obtains when the population is fixed, by adding a horizontal dimension to the constant vertical dimension, but the result is still a constant rather than an ever-rising growth rate.

There are other approaches. For instance:

  • Dinopoulos and Syropoulos (2007) explore the possibility that a growing population does not yield a faster growth rate because the increase in research capacity is offset by an increase in rent-seeking behavior.
  • Patrick Collison suggested in 2019 that researchers have gotten dramatically less productive over time due to rises in red tape and, relatedly, perhaps changes in culture. Naturally, the “progress studies” movement he helped to launch largely studies how to restore the institutions and culture that, on this view, once allowed a small number of researchers to get a lot done.

But the semi-endogenous and SWE approaches are easily the main two in the current growth theory literature.

The EA community’s use of growth theory

As far as I’m aware, when people in the EA community have used a growth model to predict the impact of advanced AI—or indeed for any other purpose—it’s almost always been semi-endogenous. Leopold Aschenbrenner used the semi-endogenous approach in the original draft of his (originally 2019) paper on existential risk and growth; Anton Korinek and I use it almost exclusively when discussing the automation of R&D in our (originally 2020) literature review on AI and growth; Davidson (2021) predominantly endorses the semi-endogenous approach when evaluating the growth impact of advanced AI; Davidson (2022) uses it when evaluating whether Open Phil should fund basic science; Erdil et al. (2023) use it in their survey paper on estimating the technology production function; and Davidson et al. (2025) and the Epoch team (2025) use it in their respective models of the feedback loops underlying an intelligence explosion.

On (a standard implementation of) the semi-endogenous approach, the developed world is already growing about as fast as it can. Since both schools agree that the main bottleneck to output at a given time is lack of labor, and since on a semi-endogenous growth account the main bottleneck to growth in output per unit of labor is a lack of R&D talent broadly construed, relieving these bottlenecks through automation will accelerate growth dramatically. Even sufficiently partially automating production and R&D is enough to make growth hyperbolic.[1]

My own best guess is that the idea behind the semi-endogenous approach—that it’s harder to make technological progress when technology is further advanced—is responsible for most of the long slowdown in technological progress per unit of research effort. But not all, even on my inside view; and my outside view can’t ignore the fact that a lot of growth theorists believe the SWE story.[2] Bloom et al. (2020) tried to settle the debate by showing that a growth in research effort has been necessary to sustain exponential growth even in our efficiency at producing various individual goods, but they didn’t. As Aghion et al. (2025) point out, this observation is compatible with the possibility that the number of product lines remains proportional to the population, but that when vertical innovation on a given product gets too difficult, entrepreneurs replace it with a new product with room for vertical innovation.

All told, I've been a bit worried for a while that the EA community has anchored too much on the semi-endogenous view, due to flukes like the fact that its main proponent (Chad Jones) has also long been interested in AI, x-risk, and the long term, and the fact that various EA researchers (including Tom Davidson and me) happen to find it compelling.

A new challenge for the SWE approach

So I figured that, instead of yet another refinement of the semi-endogenous take on automation and growth, it might be worth doing a first-pass look at what the impact of automation on growth will be if the SWE approach is right after all. In the process I noticed something strange about SWE models that hadn’t been noted in the literature before.

Davidson (2021) made me suspect the issue by helpfully noting that one SWE paper, Peretto (2018), under most parameter values implies that if only we fixed the range of products and kept our total R&D efforts fixed, growth would be hyperbolic. It turns out that the issue is much more pervasive, and much worse. Almost all SWE papers, including Peretto (2018) under all parameter values, imply that if we quickly shrank the range of products, we could produce infinite real GDP in arbitrarily little time![3] What happens is:

  1. The reason why growth is exponential with a fixed population is that a fixed population doesn’t spread its research effort across an ever wider array of products. To conclude that this isn’t wildly inefficient, we say that it’s possible to make up for a lack of new products with sufficiently large quantities of the old products.
  2. But by stipulation, with a constant number of researchers per product, growth is exponential. So if we shrank the range of products to zero, then even with a fixed population, growth in the remaining products would be superexponential. By (1), this would make up for the lack of variety. The faster we shrink the range, the better.

Taken literally, this conclusion relies on the assumption that the range of products is a continuum (so it can shrink toward zero) and that it’s feasible to instantaneously reallocate research effort from one product to another. But even if we acknowledge some frictions of this sort, the conclusion that it would be extremely, extremely desirable to shrink the range of products (and subsidize R&D on the existing range, so people do it despite not getting a monopoly afterward) seems hard to avoid within a standard SWE model. This seems implausible on its face, and especially implausible when we remember that any country, or even firm or philanthropic organization, could have implemented it this whole time.

Two responses, and their implications for the growth impact of automation

Only one SWE model avoids a conclusion along these lines: the first one, Young (1998). It avoids the conclusion by positing that vertical innovation faces severely diminishing returns to research labor, so that in effect, a larger population can only be employed productively in research if the range of goods widens.

So it seems that, if we accept the SWE approach, there are basically two possibilities. As it happens, they respectively widen the range of possibilities around the baseline of “hyperbolic growth past some automation threshold” we would get from a semi-endogenous model.

First, maybe there are severely diminishing returns to investments in vertical innovation. In the extreme case, maybe the exponential growth rate in how efficiently we can produce any given product is bounded above by some g, no matter how many people (or automated researchers) are working simultaneously on improving this efficiency. This doesn’t seem so crazy to me: maybe no research team, however large or brilliant, could double the process efficiency of a given assembly line (let alone supply chain) in five minutes. On this view, even in the event of full automation, output will grow at best double-exponentially, like : fixing process efficiency, output would grow exponentially, as the robots build more robots, but the rate at which the robots self-replicate is itself growing exponentially. In this case, the growth rate rises without bound after full automation, but it may rise relatively slowly.

Second, and I think much less plausibly, maybe economic growth has proceeded insanely inefficiently this whole time. We could have had hyperbolic growth all along by focusing our research efforts on a narrow range of products, but because each entrepreneur needs a new patent or trade secret, we keep pouring immense resources into reinventing the wheel, and all we get for it is a mildly desirable increase in the variety of wheels to buy. In this case, we will be able to get extremely fast growth simply by creating automated researchers that can coordinate well enough to avoid this issue, even if they can’t self-replicate or build anything at all, and even if they’re no smarter or more numerous than the population of human researchers generations ago.

  1. ^

    See Aghion et al. (2019), Section 4.1, example 3. For a corrected proof see Trammell and Korinek (2023), Section 6.

  2. ^

    See the paper for an up-to-date literature review. I do think a disproportionate number of growth theorists wind up writing about the SWE approach because it’s trickier to get it to work: the same reason I and many utilitarians give for why relatively few moral philosophers are utilitarians. If you think Bentham solved ethics in 1861, or Jones solved growth in 1995, you’re more likely to work on problems you see as unsolved. Still, while some position remains a common view in its academic field I'm reluctant to completely dismiss it.

  3. ^

    It's pretty obvious once you see it, but no one in the Stanford growth group, including Jones—and, as far as I can tell, none of the SWE authors I’ve emailed—had noticed this!

Comments8


Sorted by Click to highlight new comments since:

Thanks for sharing this!

Your last paragraph reminded me of this blog post from Robin, where he argued

Imagine that we made just as many cars, houses, clothes, meals, furniture, etc., each one just as big with just as high quality materials and craftsmanship. But instead of the making these in the stupefying variety that we do today, imagine that we made only a few standard variations, and didn’t update those variations as often. A few standard cars, standard clothes, standard meals, etc. Enough variety to handle different climates, body sizes, and food allergies, but not remotely enough to let each person look unique. (An exception might be made for variety in music, books, movies, etc., since these are such a tiny fraction of total costs.)

I’d guess that this alternative could plausibly cost three to ten times or more less than what we pay now. Let me explain.

Thanks, that's a great blog post and very relevant!

I don't think I agree with Robin's proposal that the main reason for all this product proliferation is that we want to have unique items--it seems to me that we have a lot of proliferation in domains where we aren't particularly keen on expressing ourselves, like brands of pencils, consistent with the standard explanation that each entrepreneur needs a tiny bit of market power to profit from his/her innovation. But whatever the reason, I agree that Robin could well be right that in some sense we get way too much (trivially distinct) product variety by default.

Very cool stuff. Thanks for writing it up! 

I agree! It is wonderful that actual academics post on this forum!

Great paper, as always Phil. 

I'm curious to hear your thoughts a bit more about if we can salvage SWE by introducing non-standard preferences. 

Minor quibble: "There is then no straightforward sense in which economic growth has historically been exponential, the central stylized fact which SWE and semi-endogenous models both seek to explain" 

I agree that there is no consumption aggregate under non-homothetic preferences, but we can still say economic growth has been exponential in the sense that GDP growth is exponential. Perhaps it is not a very meaningful number under non-homothetic preferences, as you have argued elsewhere, but it still exists. Do you have thoughts on why GDP growth has been exponential in a model without a consumption aggregate? 

Thanks!

And yeah, that's fair. One possible SWE-style story I sort of hint at there is that we have preferences like the ones I use in the horses paper; process efficiency for any given product grows exponentially with a fixed population; and there are fixed labor costs to producing any given product. In this case, it's clear that measured GDP/capita growth will be exponential (but all "vertical") with a fixed population. But if you set things up in just the right way, so that measured GDP always increases by the same proportion when the range of products increases by some marginal proportion, it will also be exponential with a growing population ("vertical"+"horizontal").

But I think it's hard to not have this all be a bit ad-hoc / knife-edge. E.g. you'll typically have to start out ever less productive at making the new products, or else the contribution to real GDP of successive % increases in the product range will blow up: as you satiate in existing products, you're willing to trade ever more of them for a proportional increase in variety. Alternatively, you can say that the range of products grows subexponentially when the population grows exponentially, because the fixed costs of the later products are higher.

Thanks for this Phil,

A couple of questions regarding SWE:

“Second-wave endogenous” (I’ll write “SWE”) growth models posit instead that technology grows exponentially with a constant or with a growing population. The idea is that process efficiency—the quantity of a given good producible with given labor and/or capital inputs—grows exponentially with constant research effort, as in a first-wave endogenous model; but when population grows, we develop more goods, leaving research effort per good fixed.

 

Only one SWE model avoids a conclusion along these lines: the first one, Young (1998). It avoids the conclusion by positing that vertical innovation faces severely diminishing returns to research labor, so that in effect, a larger population can only be employed productively in research if the range of goods widens.

So does this mean that in the research production function, the exponent on the stock of 'ideas' is one, and the exponent on the number of researchers is significantly less than one? It might be nice to see the equation.

Relatedly, isn't endogenous growth a knife-edge case? Intuitively, it seems unlikely to be true, and SWE doesn't seem to address this issue.

In Young's case the exponent on ideas is one, and progress looks like log(log(researchers)). (You need to pay a fixed cost to make the good at all in a given period, so only if you go above that do you make positive progress.) See Section 2.2.

Peretto (2018) and Massari and Peretto (2025) have SWE models that I think do successfully avoid the knife-edge issue (or "linearity critique"), but at the cost of, in some sense, digging the hole deeper when it comes to the excess variety issue.

Curated and popular this week
 ·  · 22m read
 · 
The cause prioritization landscape in EA is changing. Prominent groups have shut down, others have been founded, and everyone’s trying to figure out how to prepare for AI. This is the third in a series of posts critically examining the state of cause prioritization and strategies for moving forward. Executive Summary * An increasingly common argument is that we should prioritize work in AI over work in other cause areas (e.g. farmed animal welfare, reducing nuclear risks) because the impending AI revolution undermines the value of working in those other areas. * We consider three versions of the argument: * Aligned superintelligent AI will solve many of the problems that we currently face in other cause areas. * Misaligned AI will be so disastrous that none of the existing problems will matter because we’ll all be dead or worse. * AI will be so disruptive that our current theories of change will all be obsolete, so the best thing to do is wait, build resources, and reformulate plans until after the AI revolution. * We identify some key cruxes of these arguments, and present reasons to be skeptical of them. A more direct case needs to be made for these cruxes before we rely on them in making important cause prioritization decisions. * Even on short timelines, the AI transition may be a protracted and patchy process, leaving many opportunities to act on longer timelines. * Work in other cause areas will often make essential contributions to the AI transition going well. * Projects that require cultural, social, and legal changes for success, and projects where opposing sides will both benefit from AI, will be more resistant to being solved by AI. * Many of the reasons why AI might undermine projects in other cause areas (e.g. its unpredictable and destabilizing effects) would seem to undermine lots of work on AI as well. * While an impending AI revolution should affect how we approach and prioritize non-AI (and AI) projects, doing this wisel
 ·  · 4m read
 · 
TLDR When we look across all jobs globally, many of us in the EA community occupy positions that would rank in the 99.9th percentile or higher by our own preferences within jobs that we could plausibly get.[1] Whether you work at an EA-aligned organization, hold a high-impact role elsewhere, or have a well-compensated position which allows you to make significant high effectiveness donations, your job situation is likely extraordinarily fortunate and high impact by global standards. This career conversations week, it's worth reflecting on this and considering how we can make the most of these opportunities. Intro I think job choice is one of the great advantages of development. Before the industrial revolution, nearly everyone had to be a hunter-gatherer or a farmer, and they typically didn’t get a choice between those. Now there is typically some choice in low income countries, and typically a lot of choice in high income countries. This already suggests that having a job in your preferred field puts you in a high percentile of job choice. But for many in the EA community, the situation is even more fortunate. The Mathematics of Job Preference If you work at an EA-aligned organization and that is your top preference, you occupy an extraordinarily rare position. There are perhaps a few thousand such positions globally, out of the world's several billion jobs. Simple division suggests this puts you in roughly the 99.9999th percentile of job preference. Even if you don't work directly for an EA organization but have secured: * A job allowing significant donations * A position with direct positive impact aligned with your values * Work that combines your skills, interests, and preferred location You likely still occupy a position in the 99.9th percentile or higher of global job preference matching. Even without the impact perspective, if you are working in your preferred field and preferred country, that may put you in the 99.9th percentile of job preference
 ·  · 6m read
 · 
I am writing this to reflect on my experience interning with the Fish Welfare Initiative, and to provide my thoughts on why more students looking to build EA experience should do something similar.  Back in October, I cold-emailed the Fish Welfare Initiative (FWI) with my resume and a short cover letter expressing interest in an unpaid in-person internship in the summer of 2025. I figured I had a better chance of getting an internship by building my own door than competing with hundreds of others to squeeze through an existing door, and the opportunity to travel to India carried strong appeal. Haven, the Executive Director of FWI, set up a call with me that mostly consisted of him listing all the challenges of living in rural India — 110° F temperatures, electricity outages, lack of entertainment… When I didn’t seem deterred, he offered me an internship.  I stayed with FWI for one month. By rotating through the different teams, I completed a wide range of tasks:  * Made ~20 visits to fish farms * Wrote a recommendation on next steps for FWI’s stunning project * Conducted data analysis in Python on the efficacy of the Alliance for Responsible Aquaculture’s corrective actions * Received training in water quality testing methods * Created charts in Tableau for a webinar presentation * Brainstormed and implemented office improvements  I wasn’t able to drive myself around in India, so I rode on the back of a coworker’s motorbike to commute. FWI provided me with my own bedroom in a company-owned flat. Sometimes Haven and I would cook together at the residence, talking for hours over a chopping board and our metal plates about war, family, or effective altruism. Other times I would eat at restaurants or street food booths with my Indian coworkers. Excluding flights, I spent less than $100 USD in total. I covered all costs, including international transportation, through the Summer in South Asia Fellowship, which provides funding for University of Michigan under