Hide table of contents

How impactful is it to try to become a grantmaker focused on pressing world problems? Encouraged by Nuno’s tweet, I spent a couple of hours trying to find out.

TL;DR

I estimate the expected x-risk basis points reduced for the prospective marginal grantmaker to be 0.12 (with enormous error bars and caveats).

Background

Epistemic status: I have zero grantmaking experience and haven’t even double-checked my numbers; please do not use this post for anything that relies on it not containing serious errors.

My estimand is something like: “expected x-risk basis points reduced for the prospective marginal grantmaker doing their best to benefit the most pressing problems at an Open Philanthropy-equivalent organization.”

BOTEC

Chance of getting a job

I make guesses of

  1. the number of employers that might be possible to work at,
  2. the Open Philanthropy-equivalentness of employers, and
  3. the probability of acceptance for any particular job application.

Multiplying these factors together gives me a probability of succeeding in getting an Open Philanthropy-equivalent grantmaking job offer at (at least) one of the Open Philanthropy-equivalent organizations of 7% (on average). Seems not-crazy.

Impact from grantmaking

I used recent data from these charts to guess the total longtermist grants given per year by Open Philanthropy-equivalent organizations going forwards.

The fraction of grants a prospective grantmaker is responsible for is given by the reciprocal of my guess of the number of grantmaker-equivalents at Open Philanthropy-equivalent organizations. (I apologize for phrasing...)

Only a fraction of the grants that a grantmaker is responsible for can be counterfactually attributed to them — some grants would make for such obvious decisions that the counterfactual grantmaker would have acted identically. I convert the vibes from this post into a fraction of grants worth deliberating over (on average, 13%).

I set the ratio of skill vs. a replacement grantmaker to be mean 1.2 with mass either side of 1. This reflects the fact grantmakers may be better or worse than their counterfactual replacement, but also that on average their being hired implies that they are expected to perform better.

Taken together, I get a mean estimate of $5.7m for the Open Philanthropy-equivalent resources counterfactually moved by grantmaking activities of the prospective marginal grantmaker, conditional on job offer.

Impact from other paths

Linch claims that some fraction of grantmakers' impact comes from things that look like ‘improving all grantmaking processes at their organization,’ ‘improving the work/selection of their grantees,’ and other paths that I did not attempt to categorize. I add the categorized paths in to my estimate of impact.

My mean estimate for the Open Philanthropy-equivalent impact from non-grantmaking activities sums to around $30m (equivalent). ~70% of this comes from improving all grantmaking, ~30% from improving grantees.

Units

In order to calculate impact for the whole career path, I multiply annual impact by the number of years employed as a grantmaker.

Finally, to convert impact into terms of x-risk basis points, I divide by USD per x-risk basis point. Estimates for this quantity come from this comment.

Putting everything together

All considered, I get an estimate of the x-risk basis points reduced by the prospective marginal grantmaker of 0.12 in expectation. There is a ~27% chance of having a negative counterfactual impact (vs. replacement grantmaker) and a ~5% chance of having an impact greater than expected.

For full details, see my code in the appendix.

Limitations

There might be over- or under-counting issues. For instance, I guess that the average number of years employed will be 11. This corresponds to me excluding the impact of the grantmaker’s post-grantmaking career from my definition of career path. Several possible implementation choices seem valid here.

It goes without saying that personal factors (chance of getting jobs, grantmaker skill, etc.) could change the numbers significantly. As could cause area, changes in funding landscape, changes in Open Philanthropy-equivalentness of other organizations, etc..

I’ve ignored the Shapley values debate.

Several of the distributions that I have made guesses for could quite easily come from actual data instead — e.g. the chance of getting any particular grantmaking job, and Open Philanthropy grant amounts.

Appendix

Here’s the code! You can mess around with it in squiggle playground.

// chance of success
n_organisations_available = truncateLeft((3 to 30) - 1, 0)

organisation_op_equivalent = 0.01 to 1

n_op_equivalent = 1 + (n_organisations_available * organisation_op_equivalent)

probability_get_particular_job = truncate(0.001  to 0.1, 0, 1)

probability_get_any_job = 1 - (1 - probability_get_particular_job)^n_op_equivalent

// share of grants receive credit for
op_annual_grants = mx(normal(200M, 50M), 100M to 1B, 30M to 3B, [0.5, 0.2, 0.3])

fraction_of_annual_grants = 1 / truncateLeft(mx([1 to 100, 10 to 100, 1 to 1000], [0.2, 0.5, 0.3]), 1)

// impact from grantmaking
fraction_worth_deliberating = truncate(normal(0.1, 0.1), 0, 1)

skill_vs_replacement_grantmaker = 0.3 to 3

impact_grantmaking = op_annual_grants *
    fraction_of_annual_grants *
    fraction_worth_deliberating *
    skill_vs_replacement_grantmaker
    
// other paths to impact
improve_grantmaking_process = op_annual_grants *
    (mx([normal(1, 0.003), 1 to 3, 1 to 10], [0.98, 0.01, 0.01]) - 1)

improve_grantees = op_annual_grants *
    fraction_of_annual_grants *
    (mx(normal(1, 0.003), 0.3 to 3, 0.3 to 10, [0.7, 0.2, 0.1]) - 1)

impact_other_paths = improve_grantmaking_process + improve_grantees

// expected years employed, ignoring exogenous x-risk
years_employed = truncateRight(1 to 50, 60)

// conversion to basis points of existential risk reduced
usd_per_basis_point_xrisk = truncate(mx(normal(300M, 300M), 30M to 1B), 30M, 3B)

// final estimate
impact = probability_get_any_job *
    (impact_grantmaking + impact_other_paths) *
    years_employed /
    usd_per_basis_point_xrisk
Comments17


Sorted by Click to highlight new comments since:

It would be interesting to see estimates that compare the impact of grantmaking with the impact of researching or entrepreneurship. Because many factors are hard to estimate at an absolute level, but could be held fixed across those cases, such as "your overall level of talent", "the value of X units of x-risk reduction research", and so on. And besides, a comparison would be more decision-relevant for people.

I think this would be valuable, but doing this across various careers might be too much for any one person. But posts like this are a good first step which makes that later comparison step easier.

Agreed! Especially since Charity Entrepreneurship is starting efforts in health security, and I'd expect increasing longtermist entrepreneurship efforts over the next few years.

Love seeing this type of thinking on the Forum. Thanks for writing.

Thanks for the post! In addition to the caveats you mention, I'm a bit worried that many of your numbers came from me, especially as I'm a fairly junior (and also part-time) grantmaker. Not that I'm saying I have much better numbers now (otherwise I'd just update towards them). But just wanted to  flag a potential issue with deference cascades.

Thank you for flagging!

For interested onlookers, note that my use of Linch’s numbers leads to:

  1. ~6x increase in grantmaker impact (due to non-grantmaking activities). Probably tonnes of room for disagreement.
  2. ~0.13x multiplier due to the proportion of grants where grantmakers can make a counterfactual difference. Probably not much more than 0.5-1 orders of magnitude available for disagreement.
  3. ~300M $/x-risk basis point estimate. Probably not much more than 1-2 order of magnitude available for disagreement.

Ok, so here is how I am thinking about this.

What Joel is doing

You can divide your estimate between:

  1. The impact per year of an Open Philanthropy-equivalent grantmaking role.
  2. The chance you can get one such, and the number of years.

To estimate 1., you look at:

  • The number of funds you would be responsible for
  • The share of the impact that those funds cause that can be attributed to you, e.g., vs your counterfactual
  • Other benefits from being a good grantmaker.
  • Their conversion between funds affected and basis points of x-risk.

To estimate 2., you look at:

  • The number of organizations, and their relative value vs Open Philanthropy
  • The probability that you would get hired by each

Nitpicks:

  • I am not sure whether you are considering that if you arrive at a smaller org, you will probably be responsible for a greater % of their funding.
  • Probabilities of getting hired are not independent, e.g., a "desirable grantmaker" would probably be
  • Probability of getting hired probably should  be a beta, rather than I lognormal? Feels right, though I don't really have many intuitions for the beta

What I would do to improve this.

I think I'd first simplify the problem and look at only 1., and leave 2. (probability of getting a job, number of such jobs available) for later.

Then, I'd want to:

  1. Have a really clear model, which can be very well maintained.
  2. Get better estimates of how much money each grantmaker at Open Philanthropy is moving
  3. Have the model output all of:
  • Dollars of money the grantmaker will move
  • Dollars the grantmaker would be responsible for (probably including Shapley values)
  • Expected reduction in x-risk, but based on looking at past OP grants, rather than relying on Linch's estimates

"What I would do to improve this" should read "what I would do to build upon this". I think that most of the value of this particular estimation lies in the scenario where I/others use it to build a selection of impacts for various career paths, which allows for relative value comparisons between career paths.

Thank you for feedback, Nuno!

I totally agree that part 2 is an unhelpful distraction at this stage. (Agreed with your other points at time of writing!)

Good post (I think, without checking numbers).

probability_get_any_job depends a lot on the person. Also note that if you attempt to do grantmaking but don't get a job, you still get most of the impact of your default career. So the "try to do grantmaking" action is worth a lot more than P(become a grantmaker)*EV(grantmaking).

I suspect that usd_per_basis_point_xrisk is doing a lot of work, and different people will have pretty different beliefs about it, and maybe in particular the best grants are extremely likely to be made without the marginal grantmaker.

Thank you! On your points:

Probability of getting any Open Philanthropy-equivalent job

probability_get_any_job depends a lot on the person.

Totally agree! For reference, here's what impact looks like if you set probability_get_any_job to 0.01

or 0.3

Broader value due to trying for grantmaking jobs

note that if you attempt to do grantmaking but don't get a job, you still get most of the impact of your default career. So the "try to do grantmaking" action is worth a lot more than P(become a grantmaker)*EV(grantmaking).

Yes! This is what I am trying to get at by: "There might be over- or under-counting issues. For instance, I guess that the average number of years employed will be 11. This corresponds to me excluding the impact of the grantmaker’s post-grantmaking career from my definition of career path." But modeling out the value of career paths attempted instead and their respective probabilities sounds awful :P

Should be fine as long as you don't (1) compare different career paths using very dissimilar career path lengths, and (2) think exit options have different EV ex ante, conditional on the person's characteristics. (2) looks fishy -- I'm sure there's much room for improvement there.

Sensitivity to $/x-risk basis point

I suspect that usd_per_basis_point_xrisk is doing a lot of work, and different people will have pretty different beliefs about it

Agree again! Although I am more pessimistic! I think that we can't disagree about this parameter by much more than 1 order of magnitude, whereas there might be other parameters that have even wider scope for disagreement (or error).

For reference, here's what impact looks like if you set usd_per_basis_point_xrisk to 100M

or 1B

I guess my preferred solution to the probability_get_any_job issue is generally to just effectively set it to 1. That way you can answer the question "impact of a grantmaker" rather than "impact of trying to be a grantmaker," and the counterfactual impact of trying to become a grantmaker is P(become a grantmaker)*EV(grantmaking) with opportunity cost depending on your circumstances.

Makes sense! Would add another 0.5 orders of magnitude vs. the unconditional estimate, so ~2 x-risk basis points.

"I estimate the expected x-risk basis points reduced for the prospective marginal grantmaker to be 0.12 (with enormous error bars and caveats)."

I think it would be more understandable to present this as 1 out of X. Also, is this relative or absolute risk reduction?

A basis point is 0.01% absolute risk, so 0.12 basis points corresponds to 0.0012% change in absolute risk, or 1 in (1 / (0.0012/100)) = 1 in 83,000 change in absolute risk.

Thanks for writing this! I'm glad to see more concrete modeling like this. A few concerns/questions:

A 7% probability of getting an OP-equivalent grantmaking job seems high to me, but I might not have a good sense of what roles are out there.

How many (impact-weighted?) roles are there, and at what orgs?

I'd also worry about self-selection and invitations (to apply) to become a grantmaker skewing things.

Answering in turn:

A 7% probability of getting an OP-equivalent grantmaking job seems high to me

It comes from this number of relevant organizations

this level of Open Philanthropy-ness of those organizations

and this probability of succeeding in any particular job application

I'm sure all of these are wrong/up for debate!

How many (impact-weighted?) roles are there, and at what orgs?

Impact weighting is done at the org-level, above. The number of applicants is the reciprocal of the fraction of grants the grantmaker is responsible for (so, on average, 1/0.082 = 12, although this is driven by 25% of Open Philanthropy-equivalent organizations with smaller effective staffs).

Lots to debate here too! You can look into this yourself by copy-pasting the code into squiggle playground.

I'd also worry about self-selection and invitations (to apply) to become a grantmaker skewing things.

"Skewing" undersells the issue! It would totally change the calculations. You can see more in the first part of this comment.

Curated and popular this week
 ·  · 7m read
 · 
This is a linkpost for a paper I wrote recently, “Endogenous Growth and Excess Variety”, along with a summary. Two schools in growth theory Roughly speaking: In Romer’s (1990) growth model, output per person is interpreted as an economy’s level of “technology”, and the economic growth rate—the growth rate of “real GDP” per person—is proportional to the amount of R&D being done. As Jones (1995) pointed out, populations have grown greatly over the last century, and the proportion of people doing research (and the proportion of GDP spent on research) has grown even more quickly, yet the economic growth rate has not risen. Growth theorists have mainly taken two approaches to reconciling [research] population growth with constant economic growth. “Semi-endogenous” growth models (introduced by Jones (1995)) posit that, as the technological frontier advances, further advances get more difficult. Growth in the number of researchers, and ultimately (if research is not automated) population growth, is therefore necessary to sustain economic growth. “Second-wave endogenous” (I’ll write “SWE”) growth models posit instead that technology grows exponentially with a constant or with a growing population. The idea is that process efficiency—the quantity of a given good producible with given labor and/or capital inputs—grows exponentially with constant research effort, as in a first-wave endogenous model; but when population grows, we develop more goods, leaving research effort per good fixed. (We do this, in the model, because each innovator needs a monopoly on his or her invention in order to compensate for the costs of developing it.) Improvements in process efficiency are called “vertical innovations” and increases in good variety are called “horizontal innovations”. Variety is desirable, so the one-off increase in variety produced by an increase to the population size increases real GDP, but it does not increase the growth rate. Likewise exponential population growth raise
 ·  · 4m read
 · 
Sometimes working on animal issues feels like an uphill battle, with alternative protein losing its trendy status with VCs, corporate campaigns hitting blocks in enforcement and veganism being stuck at the same percentage it's been for decades. However, despite these things I personally am more optimistic about the animal movement than I have ever been (despite following the movement for 10+ years). What gives? At AIM we think a lot about the ingredients of a good charity (talent, funding and idea) and more and more recently I have been thinking about the ingredients of a good movement or ecosystem that I think has a couple of extra ingredients (culture and infrastructure). I think on approximately four-fifths of these prerequisites the animal movement is at all-time highs. And like betting on a charity before it launches, I am far more confident that a movement that has these ingredients will lead to long-term impact than I am relying on, e.g., plant-based proteins trending for climate reasons. Culture The culture of the animal movement in the past has been up and down. It has always been full of highly dedicated people in a way that is rare across other movements, but it also had infighting, ideological purity and a high level of day-to-day drama. Overall this made me a bit cautious about recommending it as a place to spend time even when someone was sold on ending factory farming. But over the last few years professionalization has happened, differences have been put aside to focus on higher goals and the drama overall has gone down a lot. This was perhaps best embodied by my favorite opening talk at a conference ever (AVA 2025) where Wayne and Lewis, leaders with very different historical approaches to helping animals, were able to share lessons, have a friendly debate and drive home the message of how similar our goals really are. This would have been nearly unthinkable decades ago (and in fact resulted in shouting matches when it was attempted). But the cult
 ·  · 4m read
 · 
TLDR When we look across all jobs globally, many of us in the EA community occupy positions that would rank in the 99.9th percentile or higher by our own preferences within jobs that we could plausibly get.[1] Whether you work at an EA-aligned organization, hold a high-impact role elsewhere, or have a well-compensated position which allows you to make significant high effectiveness donations, your job situation is likely extraordinarily fortunate and high impact by global standards. This career conversations week, it's worth reflecting on this and considering how we can make the most of these opportunities. Intro I think job choice is one of the great advantages of development. Before the industrial revolution, nearly everyone had to be a hunter-gatherer or a farmer, and they typically didn’t get a choice between those. Now there is typically some choice in low income countries, and typically a lot of choice in high income countries. This already suggests that having a job in your preferred field puts you in a high percentile of job choice. But for many in the EA community, the situation is even more fortunate. The Mathematics of Job Preference If you work at an EA-aligned organization and that is your top preference, you occupy an extraordinarily rare position. There are perhaps a few thousand such positions globally, out of the world's several billion jobs. Simple division suggests this puts you in roughly the 99.9999th percentile of job preference. Even if you don't work directly for an EA organization but have secured: * A job allowing significant donations * A position with direct positive impact aligned with your values * Work that combines your skills, interests, and preferred location You likely still occupy a position in the 99.9th percentile or higher of global job preference matching. Even without the impact perspective, if you are working in your preferred field and preferred country, that may put you in the 99.9th percentile of job preference